Great Deal! Get Instant $10 FREE in Account on First Order + 10% Cashback on Every Order Order Now

1 ECON7012/ECON8012 Topics in Applied Microeconomics / Applied Microeconomics Topics Take-Home Test 2 Due Wednesday 13 May at 6pm, 2020 INSTRUCTIONS: 1. This take-home test must be completed alone and...

1 answer below »
1



ECON7012/ECON8012
Topics in Applied Microeconomics / Applied Microeconomics Topics
Take-Home Test 2
Due Wednesday 13 May at 6pm, 2020
INSTRUCTIONS:
1. This take-home test must be completed alone and submitted electronically via the link
provided on iLearn. Please note Macquarie University uses ‘Turnitin’ plagiarism detection
software for all electronic submissions. Any evidence of collusion will be considered in
each
of the University’s policies relating to Academic Integrity.

2. The test is ‘open book’ meaning that you may consult the relevant papers that have been
studied in class. However, you should use your own language to answer the questions.
Paraphrasing sections from the paper is not acceptable and is also in
each of University
policies relating to Academic Integrity unless due acknowledgment has been made, e.g. use
of quotation marks and reference to page number(s).

3. The test will be open for 24 hours from Tuesday 12 May from 6pm until Wednesday 13 May
6pm. You must submit prior to this time or you will receive a mark of zero.

4. Answer all questions on the formatted Microsoft Word document provided on iLearn
(test2_answer_template.docx). Note that you should NOT restate the questions in the new
document. You do not need to provide a reference list for this test.

5. Please take note of word limit for each question. You do not have to write this many words,
ut this is an upper limit of what you can write. Any additional words beyond the word limit
will not be considered as part of the answer.

6. There are six questions. Each question is worth 10 marks.

7. The entire test is worth 60 marks and counts towards 25% of your final mark in this unit.
2

Question 1 This question relates to the following paper:
Carpenter, C. S., & Warman, C. (2019), ‘What do bicycle helmet laws do? Evidence from Canada’,
Economic Inquiry, 57(2), XXXXXXXXXX.
With respect to models XXXXXXXXXXin Table 5, explain how each of the robustness checks support or reject
the main findings of the paper. Comment on the differences between the results with respect to all-
age laws versus youth laws. (10 marks) [Word limit 200 words]
Question 2 This question relates to the following paper:
Luo R. (2018), ‘Store
ands and retail grocery competition’, Journal of Economics & Management
Strategy, 27, 653–668.
In conceptual terms, what advantages does the random coefficients logit model have over the logit
and logit-IV models of demand? Beyond simply introducing random coefficients, the author also
allows co
elation between some of these parameters. Explain the economic intuition of the
estimated covariance parameters reported in Table XXXXXXXXXXmarks) [Word limit 200 words]
Question 3 This question relates to the following paper:
Genakos, C., Koutroumpis, P., & Pagliero, M. (2018), ‘The impact of maximum markup regulation on
prices’, The Journal of Industrial Economics, 66(2), XXXXXXXXXX.
Explain how the results reported in Tables XII and XIII support or reject the authors’ claim that the
decrease in retail prices observed after removal of mark-up regulation was the result of collusion in
the wholesales market. (10 marks) [Word limit 200 words]
Question 4 This question relates to the following paper:
Hao, Z., & Cowan, B. (2019), ‘The cross-border spillover effects of recreational marijuana
legalization’, Economic Inquiry (forthcoming).
According to the results presented in the paper, how did recreational marijuana legalisation in
Colorado and Washington affect: 1) marijuana sale and manufacture a
ests, 2) DUI a
ests, and 3)
opium and cocaine possession a
ests. What role do state-specific linear time trends play in these
esults? (10 marks) [Word limit 200 words]
Question 5 This question relates to the following paper:
Rojas, C., & Briceño, A. (2019), ‘The effects of piracy on competition: Evidence from subscription
TV’, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 63, 18-43.
Conceptually, explain the steps involved in deriving the Lerner indices and marginal costs reported in
Table 6. Also, explain the relationship with the elasticity estimates reported in Table 5. Explain how
the counterfactual reveals that the Lerner indices change when illegal alternatives are not considered.
(10 marks) [Word limit 200 words]
Question 6 This question relates to the following paper:
Marti, J., Buckell, J., Maclean, J. C. & Sindelar, J. (2019), ‘To “vape” or smoke? Experimental evidence
on adult smokers’, Economic Inquiry, 57, XXXXXXXXXX
With respect to simulations D, E, F, G, H and I considered in Table 12, discuss how the simulated
proportions of ‘E-cig considered to be healthier than T-cig’ and ‘E-cig considered as effective for
smoking cessation’ compare to the base case for dual users. (10 marks) [Word limit 200 words]

Question 1
Question 2
Question 3
Question 4
Question 5
Question 6

Instructions
ECON7012/8012 – Topic 7
Relationships between legal and illegal
markets
A/Prof Jordi McKenzie, Department of Economics
Paper Details
• Rojas, C., & Briceño, A. (2019), ‘The effects of piracy on competition: Evidence
from subscription TV’, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 63, 18-43.
Abstract
Competition studies that focus on antitrust issues (e.g. market definition, market
power) are typically conducted in markets where all firms are assumed to operate
legally (competitors are tax-abiding entities, pay for all inputs used in their production
process, have paid the proper government licenses to do so, etc.). We investigate
competition issues in a market characterized by widespread piracy: subscription TV in
Perú. Estimates suggest that 50% of subscription TV users in Perú (30% in Latin
America) use an illegal provider. We make use of a unique dataset in which
households provided crucial in- formation regarding the (il)legality of their paid TV
supplier. Using quantitative antitrust tools based on demand estimation techniques,
we study the impact that the presence of the ‘informal’ sector has on competition. Our
estimates suggest that the illegal operators constitute a close substitute for (and
henceforth significantly constrain the pricing power of ) legal operators. This finding
can have important antitrust implications: the failure to account for piracy could lead
to e
oneous conclusions regarding market power measurement and the delineation
of the relevant (antitrust) market. This may b e particularly important in several
industries (especially in the developing world) where the leading operator may be
cataloged as “dominant” only in the absence of illegal providers.
Introduction
• Empirical IO and antitrust studies have propagated in many industries and
across the world, but use has been limited in developing countries
• This paper focuses on one important that can have important implications for
empirical analyses of markets: the presence of illegal competitors
• Examine a market where service itself is legal (TV subscription), but there
are a number of providers that sell through different illegal means (piracy)
• Piracy in Perú is rampant: 50% of subscription TV users are estimated to
obtain their subscription TV signal through an illegal provide
• Data for other countries in developing world suggest problem is widespread
Introduction
• Central feature of study is the availability of data on illegal TV subscriptions
• Make use of a representative household survey administered by the
Peruvian telecom regulator in which households provided information that
allows us to determine whether the TV content supplier is illegal
• Survey contains information regarding the service, including price paid as
well as several characteristics (e.g. basic v. premium; cable v. satellite; etc.)
Introduction
• Official statistics (which exclude illegal connections) indicate that 63% of
subscription TV users served by the leading operator (Telefónica)
• Employing approach using market share to proxy for market power,
authorities might deem company as dominant (or significant market power)
• However, if include illegal connections as part of the relevant market,
Telefonica’s market share falls by more than half, to 34%
• This suggests that (ignoring usual pitfalls of using market share as proxy for
market power) antitrust authorities may obtain an e
oneous conclusion
about the existence of a dominant firm in the market
Preview of Results
• Estimates suggest that, after controlling for all product characteristics that
drive demand (as well as endogeneity), not accounting for piracy leads to
e
oneous conclusions regarding the determination of substantial market
power and the delineation of the relevant (antitrust) market
• Specifically, mark-ups of three leading (legal) operators (92% of market) are
elatively modest and similar across firms (between 33.5% and 39.7%)
― Interestingly, the largest firm, Telefónica seems to have limited market
power as it registers the lowest Lerner Index (33.5%)
• Telefónica’s diversion ratio to illegal providers (13.1%) is of similar
magnitude than that observed towards its next two largest legal competitors
(11.7% to 14.7%)
Preview of Results
• Analysis re-estimates demand and Lerner Indices removing pirate
connections from choice set (i.e. ignoring their existence)
― Find that, under this (inco
ect) counterfactual, leading operator would
egister highest mark-up of three leading operators reversing finding
obtained when piracy is accounted for in analysis
• Intuition for result is if an important competitor is not accounted for in the
analysis (fringe of illegal providers), estimation fails to capture the
competitive pressure that the removed competitor exerts over other firms
Subscription TV Market in Perú
• As of 2013, approx. 20% of Perú’s households subscribed to a legal
operato
― When considering illegal providers, this share was 40.2%
• Three main legal operators are Telefónica (under the Movistar
and),
América Móvil (under the Claro
and) and DirecTV
― All three companies belong to telecom multinationals
• Two largest operators (Telefónica and América Móvil) are multiproduct
operators, providing telecommunication services throughout the country
Subscription TV Market in Perú
• Also over 90 companies with license to operate as subscription TV providers
― Main requirement for license-holder (including three largest firms) is to
pay fees equivalent to 2% of gross revenues on regular basis
― These companies only operate at regional scale throughout country
• While smaller-scale license holders may be considered legal, also
suspected to be contributors to illegal provision through under-reporting
(declaring smaller number of subscribers reducing their regulatory fee
payment) or illegal retransmission of other operators’ signals
• Also a number of outright illegal providers
Answered Same Day May 12, 2021

Solution

Harshit answered on May 12 2021
148 Votes
Question 1
The robustness checks were concluded by a survey of approximately 7,75,000 respondents, using two way fixed effects model along with the effect of all the laws as suggested. The mandatory helmet laws affected the use of helmet and riding behavior within two sections that is 1994-1999 and 2000-2014. Two questions were answered about cycling is last quarter and the time spent cycling along with its length. As shown in table 5 of the paper, models (6) to (10) reflects the effect of helmet laws in different provinces for adults aging between 18 to 64 years. In all the displayed provinces the effect of the all-aged helmet law was better than the youth helmet law. For instance in Drop Alberta, the effect of 0.191 in all-aged helmet law but the same was at 0.0144 in the youth helmet law.
The robustness checks support the main findings of the paper that is the adults should always wear a helmet. The all-aged had no existence of a relationship between the youth cycling and the effect of all-aged helmet laws increased the use of helmet in the youth by 30% points or approximately 200%. The all-aged helmet law also enhanced the probability that adults wearing helmets by approximately 19.7-24% point or 50-65% before the adoption of the law. The all-aged laws reflected a notable increase in helmet use in youth and the adult in helmet use rather than the youth which increased the use of helmet more in youth only.
Question 2
The Logit model helps in the estimation of the demand for a huge range of products using the available market data and the price endogeneity. The random coefficients logit model provides with more realistic elasticity of demand and when the estimate of demand is better, the market power can be judges in a better manner as well help the organization with achieving its goals. The random coefficients logit model solves the problem of dimensionality by the projection of the products on a space of characteristics which forms the dimension of the given size of the space. The issue of price endogeneity exists in the logit and logit-IV models of demand for identification of price coefficient. The logit model also underestimates the coefficient of price because of the positive relationship between the unobserved demand shocks and the price of the products.
The demand model used for the results of estimation was two-staged GMM and the use of FOCs to calculate cost. Table 4 compares the estimation of demand and supply by the logit model...
SOLUTION.PDF

Answer To This Question Is Available To Download

Related Questions & Answers

More Questions »

Submit New Assignment

Copy and Paste Your Assignment Here